The Economic Defense of Sprawl (And What's Wrong With It)

Defenders of suburban expansion argue that government should build more roads in order to open up more land for housing. What's wrong with that argument?

April 14, 2019, 5:00 AM PDT

By Michael Lewyn @mlewyn


Phoenix Freeway Interchange

Tim Roberts Photography / Shutterstock

The traditional libertarian-ish argument for suburban sprawl is that it is a product of the free market, and what the free market has created, no government may tear asunder. A wide variety of popular and scholarly commentary (including plenty of my own work) has criticized this view, by pointing out that government has encouraged automobile-dependent suburbia in a wide variety of ways.

As demand for urban housing has grown, the 1990s view that consumers prefer suburbs to urban cores has become implausible. But as housing costs have exploded, a new pro-sprawl argument has risen in its stead: the theory that government-supported suburbanization makes housing more affordable by opening up new land for development. For example, in his generally worthwhile recent book Order Without Design, Alain Bertaud writes that to "maintain a responsive supply of developed land, municipalities must therefore finance and build the expansion of primary infrastructure into a city’s periphery." In the U.S. context, such "primary infrastructure" usually means sprawl-generating highways.

This argument has a significant basis in fact: sprawling American cities do generally tend to be cheaper than compact ones (though there are exceptions in both directions: walkable Philadelphia is cheaper than sprawling San Diego). But it also seems to me that sprawl is not the best way to create more housing, for several reasons.

First, although sprawl is one way to create extra land, it is not the only way to do so. As Bertaud wisely notes, a city can "create" additional land by allowing more housing on urban land. For example, if a city allowed more multistory buildings instead of reserving huge chunks of cities for single-family houses, it would essentially be creating developable land in the air, thus increasing the supply of land. Similarly, if the city allowed smaller yards, it would increase the supply of land available for housing. This need not mean a city of 90-story skyscrapers; cities could allow incremental height increases instead, so that neighborhoods now reserved for one-or two-story houses could have four-story apartment buildings, and places with four-story apartment buildings could have eight-story buildings.

Second, sprawl creates transportation costs for drivers that at least partially offset the benefits of cheap real estate. For example, a typical household in Suffolk County, Long Island (the outer suburb where I work) spends over $14,000 on transportation, while a typical household in Manhattan spends just below $6,300 and a typical household in Queens spends just over $8,200 (more data here). It could be argued that the transportation cost gap between driving and active transportation is artificially inflated by public subsidies for public transit. But if policymakers use public transit subsidies as an excuse to support pro-sprawl policies, they are creating a self-fulfilling prophecy: pro-sprawl policies force transit to cover more territory to serve the same number of people, thus making transit more expensive and increasing per-capita transit subsidies. For example, New York's subway loses less than $1 per ride, while the rail systems of sprawling cities such as Santa Clara lose far more

Third, sprawl development creates a variety of externalities that are typically not reflected in housing costs. The growth of automobile-dependent suburbs leads to increased vehicle use, which leads to increased greenhouse gas emissions and other pollution of all sorts, as well as increased likelihood of death and injury from automobile crashes.

In theory, it is possible that these externalities could be taxed and regulated away. For example, a state could calculate the social cost of automobile-related pollution, and impose a tax or fee sufficient to equal that cost. But sprawl actually makes it less likely that this could occur; when most people spend their lives inside their automobiles, they are likely to resist any attempts to tax auto use, and increased taxation of cars becomes politically radioactive. 

It could also be argued that the rise of electric cars or some other technology will wipe out the environmental impacts of cars. This argument lacks merit, because in recent years American automakers and consumers have chosen gas-guzzling, dangerous sport utility vehicles rather than energy-efficient vehicles. As a result, American vehicles are not as energy-efficient as some of their European counterparts. Moreover, a single-minded focus on miles per gallon overlooks the other externalities caused by sprawl, such as increased injuries and death from speeding vehicles.

In sum, a government that aggressively promotes sprawl development might increase the supply of housing. But there are more environmentally friendly ways of achieving the same result.


Michael Lewyn

Michael Lewyn is an associate professor at Touro College, Jacob D. Fuchsberg Law Center, in Long Island. His scholarship can be found at http://works.bepress.com/lewyn.

Indian Trail, North Carolina

Four ‘Low-Hanging Fruit’ Zoning Reforms

An excerpt from the latest book on zoning argues for four approaches to reform that can immediately improve land use regulation in the United States.

June 26, 2022 - M. Nolan Gray

Car Traffic

San Francisco Just Ended Single-Family Zoning

The San Francisco Board of Supervisors voted to Tuesday to eliminate single-family zoning, but pro-development advocates say additional changes are needed to unleash a wave of construction.

June 29, 2022 - San Francisco Chronicle

Housing Construction

The State of the Nation’s Housing: 2022 Report

An annual report from the Joint Center for Housing Studies (JCHS) reveals that a growing number of American households face housing insecurity and spiking costs of living.

June 23, 2022 - Enterprise Community Partners

Nighttime view of Oklahoma City skyline

Oklahoma City Begins Work on its First Bus Rapid Transit System

The BRT line has been in the works since 2005, when the city created a plan to focus on regional transit solutions.

1 hour ago - Mass Transit

MARTA Bus

Atlanta One Step Closer to Bus Rapid Transit

The city’s transit agency says bus rapid transit will be cheaper and faster to build than light rail.

5 hours ago - The Atlanta Journal-Constitution

Two-story housing in Sacramento, California

Sacramento Households Hit Hard by Evictions

With pandemic-era renter protections ending and rents rising by close to 20 percent, renters in Sacramento are finding it harder to afford housing in the region.

July 1 - The Sacramento Bee

New Updates on The Edge

HUD's Office of Policy Development and Research

International Real Estate Strategies and Deal Negotiation

Harvard Graduate School of Design Executive Education

Affordable Housing: Principles for Changing Domestic and Global Markets

Harvard Graduate School of Design Executive Education

Urban Design for Planners 1: Software Tools

This six-course series explores essential urban design concepts using open source software and equips planners with the tools they need to participate fully in the urban design process.

Hand Drawing Master Plans

This course aims to provide an introduction into Urban Design Sketching focused on how to hand draw master plans using a mix of colored markers.