Defenders of suburban expansion argue that government should build more roads in order to open up more land for housing. What's wrong with that argument?

The traditional libertarian-ish argument for suburban sprawl is that it is a product of the free market, and what the free market has created, no government may tear asunder. A wide variety of popular and scholarly commentary (including plenty of my own work) has criticized this view, by pointing out that government has encouraged automobile-dependent suburbia in a wide variety of ways.
As demand for urban housing has grown, the 1990s view that consumers prefer suburbs to urban cores has become implausible. But as housing costs have exploded, a new pro-sprawl argument has risen in its stead: the theory that government-supported suburbanization makes housing more affordable by opening up new land for development. For example, in his generally worthwhile recent book Order Without Design, Alain Bertaud writes that to "maintain a responsive supply of developed land, municipalities must therefore finance and build the expansion of primary infrastructure into a city’s periphery." In the U.S. context, such "primary infrastructure" usually means sprawl-generating highways.
This argument has a significant basis in fact: sprawling American cities do generally tend to be cheaper than compact ones (though there are exceptions in both directions: walkable Philadelphia is cheaper than sprawling San Diego). But it also seems to me that sprawl is not the best way to create more housing, for several reasons.
First, although sprawl is one way to create extra land, it is not the only way to do so. As Bertaud wisely notes, a city can "create" additional land by allowing more housing on urban land. For example, if a city allowed more multistory buildings instead of reserving huge chunks of cities for single-family houses, it would essentially be creating developable land in the air, thus increasing the supply of land. Similarly, if the city allowed smaller yards, it would increase the supply of land available for housing. This need not mean a city of 90-story skyscrapers; cities could allow incremental height increases instead, so that neighborhoods now reserved for one-or two-story houses could have four-story apartment buildings, and places with four-story apartment buildings could have eight-story buildings.
Second, sprawl creates transportation costs for drivers that at least partially offset the benefits of cheap real estate. For example, a typical household in Suffolk County, Long Island (the outer suburb where I work) spends over $14,000 on transportation, while a typical household in Manhattan spends just below $6,300 and a typical household in Queens spends just over $8,200 (more data here). It could be argued that the transportation cost gap between driving and active transportation is artificially inflated by public subsidies for public transit. But if policymakers use public transit subsidies as an excuse to support pro-sprawl policies, they are creating a self-fulfilling prophecy: pro-sprawl policies force transit to cover more territory to serve the same number of people, thus making transit more expensive and increasing per-capita transit subsidies. For example, New York's subway loses less than $1 per ride, while the rail systems of sprawling cities such as Santa Clara lose far more.
Third, sprawl development creates a variety of externalities that are typically not reflected in housing costs. The growth of automobile-dependent suburbs leads to increased vehicle use, which leads to increased greenhouse gas emissions and other pollution of all sorts, as well as increased likelihood of death and injury from automobile crashes.
In theory, it is possible that these externalities could be taxed and regulated away. For example, a state could calculate the social cost of automobile-related pollution, and impose a tax or fee sufficient to equal that cost. But sprawl actually makes it less likely that this could occur; when most people spend their lives inside their automobiles, they are likely to resist any attempts to tax auto use, and increased taxation of cars becomes politically radioactive.
It could also be argued that the rise of electric cars or some other technology will wipe out the environmental impacts of cars. This argument lacks merit, because in recent years American automakers and consumers have chosen gas-guzzling, dangerous sport utility vehicles rather than energy-efficient vehicles. As a result, American vehicles are not as energy-efficient as some of their European counterparts. Moreover, a single-minded focus on miles per gallon overlooks the other externalities caused by sprawl, such as increased injuries and death from speeding vehicles.
In sum, a government that aggressively promotes sprawl development might increase the supply of housing. But there are more environmentally friendly ways of achieving the same result.

Planetizen Federal Action Tracker
A weekly monitor of how Trump’s orders and actions are impacting planners and planning in America.

Canada vs. Kamala: Whose Liberal Housing Platform Comes Out on Top?
As Canada votes for a new Prime Minister, what can America learn from the leading liberal candidate of its neighbor to the north?

The Five Most-Changed American Cities
A ranking of population change, home values, and jobs highlights the nation’s most dynamic and most stagnant regions.

San Diego Adopts First Mobility Master Plan
The plan provides a comprehensive framework for making San Diego’s transportation network more multimodal, accessible, and sustainable.

Housing, Supportive Service Providers Brace for Federal Cuts
Organizations that provide housing assistance are tightening their purse strings and making plans for maintaining operations if federal funding dries up.

Op-Ed: Why an Effective Passenger Rail Network Needs Government Involvement
An outdated rail network that privileges freight won’t be fixed by privatizing Amtrak.
Urban Design for Planners 1: Software Tools
This six-course series explores essential urban design concepts using open source software and equips planners with the tools they need to participate fully in the urban design process.
Planning for Universal Design
Learn the tools for implementing Universal Design in planning regulations.
New York City School Construction Authority
Village of Glen Ellyn
Central Transportation Planning Staff/Boston Region MPO
Institute for Housing and Urban Development Studies (IHS)
City of Grandview
Harvard GSD Executive Education
Regional Transportation Commission of Southern Nevada
Toledo-Lucas County Plan Commissions
