Supply, Demand, and Housing Prices, Part 2

Rebutting arguments against the law of supply and demand.

Read Time: 5 minutes

October 27, 2015, 5:00 AM PDT

By Michael Lewyn @mlewyn


High Rise Construction

Sean Pavone / Shutterstock

Throughout the United States, rents (and in some cases housing prices) have been skyrocketing over the past several years. Under the economic law of supply and demand, one* obvious answer to this crisis is: expand supply (by which I mean, eliminate zoning regulations that prevent landowners from building more apartments.) The latter argument, of course, has met a lot of resistance from a variety of quarters. Some months ago, I critiqued what I called "supply and demand denialism."

But since then, I've heard a variety of interesting new arguments on this point, which I would like to address in this blog post. 

Argument 1: "Where land costs are high, housing costs will always be expensive." I am not persuaded by this argument, for two reasons. First, the cost of land is not the same as the cost of housing. For example, suppose that the cost of land costs $5 million per acre. Does that mean that no housing unit can cost less than $5 million? Yes, if the government only allows one housing unit to be built. But if government allows ten housing units to be built, the landowner can sell each for $500,000 and break even. And if the government allows 100 housing units to be built, the landowner can sell each for $50,000 and break even. So if people were allowed to build more housing units, the price of housing would come down—high land costs or no high land costs. 

Second, as long as some land is zoned for uses other than housing, the supply of land is not static, and, thus, the cost of land is not static. Government could zone additional land for mixed uses (or just for housing), effectively creating more land.

Argument 2: "Greedy developers build only for rich people."** But this argument begs the question: why is it that developers build only for rich people in New York but build for middle-class people in Pittsburgh or Indianapolis? Are the developers any less greedy there? Of course not! High housing costs mean that developers can get more money for their housing in New York. So this argument creates a vicious circle: government regulation causes a housing shortage, causing high housing costs, causing developers to charge more for new housing, causing citizens to use this very fact as a reason not to allow new housing, causing the housing shortage to get even worse. 

More importantly, most housing units aren't new units. When I lived in Manhattan, I lived in a gentrifying zip code (10018) with high rents and newer housing than many other neighborhoods. But even there, my last Zillow.com search found that only 9 of 47 available rentals were built before 2000. So rather than asking "why are new units more expensive?", perhaps we should be asking "why are older units so expensive?"

It seems to me that when the number of new units is restricted, only the most affluent renters can afford them. This in turn means that the upper middle class and the "ordinary rich" are then forced into the older unit market. They bid up the price of older units, forcing up the price of older units. By contrast, if more new units were permitted, the “ordinary rich” and the upper middle class could afford them, making older units more affordable for everyone else. To put it another way, if there were more newer units on the market, the aging walk-ups that now cost $2000 a month might cost, say, $1500 or $1000 per month or even less.

A variation of this argument is that "greedy developers only build condos." I'm not sure I find this persuasive because condominia and apartments aren't completely separate markets. Condos can sometimes be rented, and condos and rental units compete with each other because if condos are abundant enough and cheap enough, people who would otherwise rent buy condos (thus causing less price pressure on rentals, causing rents to become cheaper). So I'm not sure whether this argument changes the underlying economic rules.

A third argument that I mentioned, but did not address as fully as I could have, is the claim that new housing raises housing costs by making a neighborhood more desirable. This argument assumes that gentrification follows new housing, rather than vice versa.  Although more research on this issue would be useful, it seems to me that the reverse is often the case: historic neighborhoods throughout the country have been gentrifying over the last decade or two,*** and new housing follows the gentrification when zoning permits it. For example, in Greenpoint (one of Brooklyn’s most rapidly gentrifying areas) about half of all housing was built before 1950, while newer areas on Brooklyn's outskirts are not doing so well.

In sum, it seems to me that, in a world with less zoning, fewer density regulations, and more building, rents would eventually stop exploding—and that neither land costs nor the existence of rich people necessarily prevents that. 

*But not the only one. Another alternative is to build huge amounts of public housing- perhaps not a bad idea. But given the dismal reputation of public housing, the unusually high tax levels of some of the most expensive cities, and the high level of taxophobia in the United States, I cannot imagine this happening anytime soon. 

**Not dissimilar to "greedy developers only build for rich foreigners," critiqued here.

***See generally William Lucy's book "Tomorrow's CIties, Tomorrow's Suburbs" (pre-1940 neighborhoods experiencing greater income gains than postwar suburbs). 


Michael Lewyn

Michael Lewyn is an associate professor at Touro College, Jacob D. Fuchsberg Law Center, in Long Island. His scholarship can be found at http://works.bepress.com/lewyn.

The  Rue Sainte-Catherine in Bordeaux is crowded with pedestrians in a lively European scene.

European Cities Act on Density

The sprawling mass of suburbia has been a disaster for the environment. But now smaller, denser cities herald a renaissance in city living.

November 20, 2022 - Wired Magazine

Victorian two-story buildings with retail shops in downtown Nashvile, Tennessee

Nashville Sets Downtown Parking Maximums

Nashville is the latest city to enact a substantive change to the parking requirements set by the city’s zoning code—doing away with parking minimums and setting parking maximums in the city’s Urban Zoning Overlay.

November 20, 2022 - The Tennessean

Musician playing guitar in front of outdoor seating and sidewalk vendors in Houston, Texas

Houston Development Aims to Create Hyper-Walkable, Micro-Living Neighborhood

The 17-acre Second Ward project has spurred both optimism for a more walkable city and concerns about displacement and gentrification.

November 21, 2022 - Houston Chronicle

Three Lyft electric scooters parked on a sidewalk in West Los Angeles

Lyft Pulls Micromobility From Los Angeles Area

The company will no longer provide shared bikes and scooters in the L.A. region, citing a ‘lack of longterm commitment’ from cities.

November 25 - Santa Monica Daily Press

View of Duwamish River with Seattle and Mount Rainier in background

King County Water Treatment Station Set to Open

The facility is part of a plan to protect the Duwamish River from polluted runoff from overflowing sewer pipes.

November 25 - The Center Square

View of Houston buildings over White Oak Bayou

Proposed Park Yet Another Hurdle for Houston Interstate Expansion

The Interstate 45 widening project, halted by a federal order and opposed by many local officials and organizations, could hit a new snag if White Oak Bayou becomes a city park.

November 25 - Axios

Urban Design for Planners 1: Software Tools

This six-course series explores essential urban design concepts using open source software and equips planners with the tools they need to participate fully in the urban design process.

Planning for Universal Design

Learn the tools for implementing Universal Design in planning regulations.