(NOTE TO READERS: An expanded, footnote-filled version of this article is online at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1632935 ) Externalities are costs (or benefits) imposed on third parties by another individual’s voluntary action. Government regulations exist at least partially to protect us from externalities created by others.
(NOTE TO READERS: An expanded, footnote-filled version of this article is online at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1632935 )
Externalities
are costs
(or benefits) imposed on third parties by another individual's voluntary
action. Government regulations exist at least partially to protect us from externalities created by others.
But government regulation may create its own externalities, leading to costs that may even outweigh the benefits (or "positive externalities") created by regulation.
One
example of
externality-creating regulation is government-imposed minimum parking
requirements. For example, Jacksonville, Florida
requires apartment complexes to provide 1.75 parking spaces per
one-bedroom
apartment - despite the fact that 16% of Jacksonville's
renter households don't even own one
car. The purpose of such regulation is
to prevent externalities- for example, to prevent drivers from creating congestion and pollution while they cruise the streets searching for parking spaces.
But
in fact, this
sort of regulation creates a variety of negative externalities.
First, minimum parking requirements, by
artificially increasing the supply of parking, reduce the cost of
parking and
thus force landowners not only to build parking lots, but to give
parking to
motorists for free (or, in downtown areas, at lower rates than would be the case in the absence of regulation). But landowners still
have to pay to build parking lots and
garages; so landowners will pass the costs of parking lot construction on to their tenants and
customers in
the form of higher rents and prices. So as a practical matter, society as a whole is forced to subsidize driving; parking regulation makes driving cheaper by making parking free, and makes nondrivers pay more for goods and services to support this subsidy.
Second, minimum parking requirements reduce the total
amount of housing and commerce, because land that is used for parking
cannot be
used for housing or commerce. And by reducing the housing supply, minimum parking requirements reducce density- and residents of lower-density areas tend to be
highly
dependent on automobiles for most daily tasks, because they are less
likely to
live within walking distance of public transit and other amenities. So in this respect as well, minimum parking
requirements increase driving and its negative side effects.
Third,
minimum
parking requirements indirectly discourage walking, by encouraging
landowners
to surround their buildings with parking.
Where shops and offices are surrounded by a sea of parking, they
are
unpleasant places for pedestrians, because pedestrians must waste time
walking
through parking lots and risk their lives dodging automobiles. When walking is unpleasant, people drive more
and walk less.
Thus, minimum parking requirements make driving more attractive and walking less so. It logically follows that municipal parking
regulation may actually increase, rather than decreasing, congestion and pollution. And by increasing the number of parking lots,
minimum parking requirements may increase pollution from stormwater
runoff. Rainstorms cause stormwater to
fall on parking lots, collect metal, oil and other pollutants lying on
the
ground, and then to run off into nearby waters, thus making those waters
dirtier and more dangerous.
Of
course, it
could be argued that the costs of minimum parking requirements are
slight,
because in the absence of such requirements most landowners would build
almost
as much parking as they do now in order to get financing.
But this argument cuts both ways: if
landowners would build parking lots in the absence of regulation, then
the
abolition of regulation is unlikely to create negative externalities significant enough to justify regulation.

Maui's Vacation Rental Debate Turns Ugly
Verbal attacks, misinformation campaigns and fistfights plague a high-stakes debate to convert thousands of vacation rentals into long-term housing.

Planetizen Federal Action Tracker
A weekly monitor of how Trump’s orders and actions are impacting planners and planning in America.

San Francisco Suspends Traffic Calming Amidst Record Deaths
Citing “a challenging fiscal landscape,” the city will cease the program on the heels of 42 traffic deaths, including 24 pedestrians.

Half of Post-Fire Altadena Home Sales Were to Corporations
Large investors are quietly buying up dozens of properties in Altadena, California, where a devastating wildfire destroyed more than 6,000 homes in January.

Opinion: What San Francisco’s Proposed ‘Family Zoning’ Could Really Mean
Mayor Lurie is using ‘family zoning’ to encourage denser development and upzoning — but could the concept actually foster community and more human-scale public spaces?

Jacksonville Launches First Autonomous Transit Shuttle in US
A fleet of 14 fully autonomous vehicles will serve a 3.5-mile downtown Jacksonville route with 12 stops.
Urban Design for Planners 1: Software Tools
This six-course series explores essential urban design concepts using open source software and equips planners with the tools they need to participate fully in the urban design process.
Planning for Universal Design
Learn the tools for implementing Universal Design in planning regulations.
Gallatin County Department of Planning & Community Development
Heyer Gruel & Associates PA
JM Goldson LLC
City of Camden Redevelopment Agency
City of Astoria
Transportation Research & Education Center (TREC) at Portland State University
Jefferson Parish Government
Camden Redevelopment Agency
City of Claremont
