The Pretext Problem: The Pitfalls of Planning While Bargaining

Lots of planning is discretionary. Cities and developers negotiate what builders will do for cities in exchange for the right to build, creating an incentive for bad rules, eroding the public's faith in zoning, and enabling political corruption.

7 minute read

June 9, 2021, 8:00 AM PDT

By Michael Manville

@MichaelManvill6


Parking Sign

TFoxFoto / Shutterstock

In 2015, an unusual Los Angeles development controversy came to a head. A neighborhood association in Hollywood had sued the developer of a newly completed 22-story, 300-unit apartment building. By Hollywood's standard zoning, a building like this one wasn't allowed. It was taller than the neighborhood’s height limits, and—importantly—didn't have as much parking as the city usually required. It had been built nevertheless, because the developer had signed an agreement with the city that exempted the building from some regulations if the developer met a few additional conditions—namely, the city said the developer could provide fewer parking spaces if the developer preserved the façade of a Spaghetti Factory restaurant previously occupying on the site. (The Spaghetti Factory was considered a historic resource.)

The conflict arose because—according to the developer—the Spaghetti Factory turned out to be too dilapidated to save. With the city's permission, the developer demolished it and rebuilt the façade; given the circumstances, the developer said, it had fulfilled its agreement with the city. The neighborhood association disagreed, argued that the façade had been improperly demolished, and the agreement had been violated. A judge sided with the association and declared the agreement null. Once the agreement was null, the project itself was out of compliance, because (among other things) it didn't have enough parking.

There's plenty that's odd about this story, including the idea of a "historic" Spaghetti Factory. But let's focus on the curious role played by the parking requirement. By the logic of the development agreement, and thus of the lawsuit, a building without a Spaghetti Factory façade needed 300 parking spaces. The same building, on the same site, but with the façade, did not. That makes no sense. The presence or absence of a façade shouldn't change how many people drive to a building. Whatever the parking requirement was doing, it didn't have much to do with parking.

The parking requirement, in short, was pretextual: Its value to the city lay not in stated intentions of the zoning code (i.e., ensuring the presence of parking spaces), but in what developers would do to escape it. The city used the parking requirement as an indirect way to preserve historic character, not a direct way to guarantee vehicle storage. It might have been on the books as a transportation mitigation; its real purpose was as a bargaining chip.

Planning is full of such pretext. That probably isn't good for planning.

Discretion: the Mother of Pretext

Zoom back out to when this Hollywood tower was first proposed. Los Angeles had determined, years before, that it wanted Hollywood, a central area with three subway stations, to have more density. Given that fact, it's notable that the developer needed special permission to build a 22-story building. If density is the goal, why not just allow it?

The answer is that a lot of city power, especially in land use regulation, comes from discretion: the ability to selectively release some developers from some rules in exchange for community benefits like open space or affordable housing. In cities where housing demand is strong, discretion can let cities finance public services through the zoning code, and deliver those services without raising taxes.

Discretion has always been a part of planning, for the simple reason that planning rules can rarely be inviolate. Sometimes, for example, an applicant has an oddly shaped parcel or other unusual condition would need a variance even to build something simple, and consistent with the local zoning. Beginning in the 1980s, however, discretion expanded, and took on a more strategic character as a result of two factors: property tax restrictions and rising concerns about environmental quality and historic preservation. The first limited the ability of local governments to finance services through taxation. The second gave cities new regulatory power over development. In combination, cities lost fiscal autonomy but gained land use power.

Since residents still wanted services, cities started using the latter to compensate for the former, by negotiating more with developers. Want fewer parking spaces? Finance some affordable housing and we'll roll back the requirements. Want to build an extra story? Build a park and we'll relax the height limit. In California, discretion eventually became central to the state's affordable housing program. Developers can get more density and provide less parking if they contribute subsidized units.

Discretion is the mother of pretext. When cities use rules to bargain with developers, the rules quietly take on a different role. Discretionary bargaining requires both stringent regulations and a willingness to waive them, which means that in a discretionary regime, the optimal zoning code will have rules that are both onerous and (at least some of the time) unnecessary. The rules need to be onerous to get developers to the table, and unnecessary so they can be traded away at little cost.

Here, a problem arises: A zoning bylaw that contains onerous and unnecessary regulations might be good for bargaining, but it isn't a good zoning bylaw. It's no accident that parking requirements show up a lot in discretionary rulemaking. They're harmful. Almost no one believes parking requirements aren't onerous, that they have positive social value, or that cities would be worse off without them. In a world where we wanted good zoning, parking requirements look awful. But in a world where we want to use zoning to negotiate for good outcomes, parking requirements look valuable. That's one reason the California APA, as well as some affordable housing advocates, are reluctant to embrace statewide parking reform. The APA, crucially, makes no argument in favor of parking requirements. It argues only that requirements offer valuable leverage in getting developers to build affordable housing—a goal wholly unrelated to storing vehicles. That's pretext.

Pretext at the Expense of Certainty

But is pretext really so bad? One case for discretion (and pretext) is that it makes zoning more powerful, converting it from a tool that merely regulates land into a vehicle for accomplishing other goals. But discretion also deprives zoning of power, by shifting influence away from the rules themselves and toward people with the authority to change them.

That shift of influence has two consequences. First, it erodes the certainty and transparency that zoning nominally thrives on. Zoning is supposed to be a community property right, and property, as Jeremy Bentham famously said, is “nothing but a basis of expectation.” Those expectations become less reliable when the purpose of the zoning-as-written is unclear. Does a density restriction mean a community wants low density, or does it actually mean the community wants some unstated package of other improvements and will trade density to get it? No one knows until someone pulls a building permit. Selectively enforcing rules can give officials more power to accomplish short-term goals, but it risks a long-term consequence of eroding faith in the rules themselves.

Second, shifting power away from rules and toward people invites corruption. The discretionary trade in development rights, even when it is wholly legal, strikes many people as unseemly. But empowering a small group of people to offer exemptions can turn unseemly trades into illegal ones. The scandal that engulfed the Los Angeles City Council's Planning and Land Use Management (PLUM) committee in 2018 was rooted in the PLUM's discretionary power. L.A.'s zoning code is hopelessly outdated; little can be built without discretionary approvals. In a hot housing market, developers wanted extra height and more density, and some of them bribed at least one councilmember to get it. Corruption scandals, of course, also do professional planning no favors.

Zoning should be transparent. If Los Angeles wants density in its downtown and in Hollywood, it should zone for that density—not zone itself halfway there and then let the bargaining begin. Similarly, if the California APA wants to withhold its endorsement of parking reform, it should do so because it believes California has a parking shortage, not because it believes (wrongly, in my view) that cities can trade parking requirements for subsidized housing. Even if bad policies sometimes yield good outcomes, our goal should be good policies that yield good outcomes. Affordable housing, open space, and preservation are all important. For precisely that reason, we can and should build an affirmative case for them. We don't need to smuggle them into the city through our zoning regulations and risk debasing those regulations in the process.

[Note: Portions of this column are adapted from an academic article “Motivations for Growth Revolts” published in the journal City and Community.]

Michael Manville is an associate professor of Urban Planning at the University of California, Los Angeles, who studies housing, land use, and transportation.

courses user

As someone new to the planning field, Planetizen has been the perfect host guiding me into planning and our complex modern challenges. Corey D, Transportation Planner

As someone new to the planning field, Planetizen has been the perfect host guiding me into planning and our complex modern challenges.

Corey D, Transportation Planner

Ready to give your planning career a boost?

MARTA train tracks run in the middle of a six lane highway with an overpass and the Buckhead city skyline of skyscrapers in the background.

How Would Project 2025 Affect America’s Transportation System?

Long story short, it would — and not in a good way.

September 29, 2024 - Marcelo Remond

People in large plaza in front of Zurich Opera House in Switzerland.

But... Europe

European cities and nations tend to have less violent crime than the United States. Is government social welfare spending the magic bullet that explains this difference?

September 26, 2024 - Michael Lewyn

Aerial view of low-rise neighborhood in Los Angeles, California.

California Law Ends Road Widening Mandates

Housing developers will no longer be required to dedicate land to roadway widening, which could significantly reduce the cost of construction and support more housing units.

September 25, 2024 - Streetsblog California

Desert tortoise on asphalt road.

California Room to Roam Act Prioritizes Wildlife Connectivity

A new state law requires new development and infrastructure to minimize disruption to local wildlife habitats and migration patterns.

October 4 - Center for Biological Diversity

Victorian Flavel House mansion in Astoria, Oregon.

Oregon Releases Historic Preservation Plan for Next Decade

A plan from the state’s State Historic Preservation Commission outlines priorities for preserving Oregon’s cultural and historic resources.

October 4 - KTVZ

Rendering of Interstate 35 cap park over sunken freeway in Austin, Texas.

Austin’s Vision for I-35 Cap Parks Takes Final Shape

The city’s plan includes parks, entertainment pavilions, commercial space, sports fields, and other facilities over 30 acres of deck parks spanning a sunken Interstate 35.

October 4 - KUT

Urban Design for Planners 1: Software Tools

This six-course series explores essential urban design concepts using open source software and equips planners with the tools they need to participate fully in the urban design process.

Planning for Universal Design

Learn the tools for implementing Universal Design in planning regulations.

New Updates on PD&R Edge

HUDs Office of Policy Development and Research

Regional Rail at Mpact Transit + Community 2024

Mpact (formerly Rail~Volution)

Cornell's Department of City and Regional Planning Announces Undergraduate and Graduate Program Information Sessions and Application Details

Cornell University's College of Architecture, Art, and Planning (AAP), the Department of City and Regional Planning (CRP)

Write for Planetizen