When Can Economic Advocacy Succeed in City Hall?

Marc Doussard of University of Illinois guest blogs on his new work in the Journal of Planning Education and Research, available with open access through Dec. 15, 2015.

Read Time: 4 minutes

November 17, 2015, 2:00 PM PST

By JPER


Fight for 15

Dan Holm / Shutterstock

Guest Blogger: Dr. Marc Doussard 

Like a lot of planners, I came to the profession thanks to a deep conviction that cities—the worlds of our everyday lives—are the idea places from which to change society for the better. And like too many planners, my formal education amounted to something of a hazing experience: Cities' limited powers, tenuous finances, and mandates to pursue growth  over other concerns make action for economic fairness a bad idea in policy terms and a loser politically.

The Fight for 15 rally in New York city in April 2015. (Image by The All-Nite Images, via Flickr)

However, cities are now leading the way in addressing the wicked problem of economic inequality. The minimum wage will soon reach $15 in Seattle, San Francisco, and Los Angeles, $13 in Chicago, and double-digits in several other cities. On top of that, cities have taken the lead in addressing other problems, such as lack of access to childcare, declining access to sick and vacation days, wage theftm, and unpredictable schedules. This has happened even as state governments retreat from these issues.

In my recent article in the Journal of Planning Education and Research (free link until Dec. 15), I ask how this remarkable change came to be—and why it has gone unnoticed. The first question was relatively easy to answer. I compared two similar policy proposals in Chicago: A 2006 campaign for a $10 minimum wage for big box retailers, which failed, and a 2014 campaign for a $13 citywide minimum wage. 

These two campaigns were similar in most of the ways that count—they consisted of the same unions and community organizations, drew on the same research apparatus, and used similar arguments. But they differed in their approach to urban politics. The 2006 "Big Box" campaign attempted to win what scholars refer to as the “inside game” at City Hall: It counted wards, precincts, blocks and votes, made compromises to win over opponents, and tried to bargain a victory out of a hostile legislative environment. Ultimately, those tradeoffs sapped support for what appears in hindsight as a very limited policy ask: By advocating a small pay increase for a limited subset of employment, the campaign created divisions within and across the neighborhoods where it needed support.

By contrast, the 2014 minimum wage campaign achieved its goals by ignoring deal-making in City Hall. Rather than pressure the city council and the mayor to raise the pay level, the Fight for 15 campaign simply demanded a raise, and kept the issue of low pay in the news. The campaign’s success validates some of the criticisms long attached to the practice of equity planning, or the use of public power and advocacy to steer resources and power to those with few of either.

When Norm Krumholz and the Cleveland Planning Department initiated the practice in the 1970s, friendly critics warned that channeling a social movement's energies into the technical details and legislative minutiae of city government was a bad trade. Most prominently, they argued that steering advocacy from protests to policy would rob social movements of the underlying enthusiasm that constitutes their greatest power. Of equal importance is the fact that advocacy directed at City Hall activates a well-resourced and meticulously organized pro-growth coalition that can easily defeat reform legislation.

My research shows that Fight for 15 upheld the ideals of equity planning by ignoring the central tenet of working through City Hall. The campaign made a big demand, and did not tie that demand to any particular bill or legislative bloc, which allowed its organizers to generate political pressure that ultimately compelled Chicago's mayor to act on his own.

A Fight for 15 rally in Chicago, July 2013. (Image by Madmanmikey, via Flickr)

Why, then, has this remarkable development in urban policy received so little discussion? Regardless of their long-term impacts, municipal minimum wages are a remarkable phenomenon for the simple fact that they have won support from legislative bodies hardwired to oppose them. Why hasn't this transformation drawn more scrutiny? A lot of the answer goes to changes in how we understand our work as planners. Community and economic development have always occupied an uncomfortable place within planning, for the simple fact that they are open-ended, constrained, indirect, and political. Like many people who practice economic development, I envy the comparative simplicity and authority of land use planning. Because community and economic development involve politics, and because their practice involves indirect power, they don't look like other types of planning. They're certainly not amenable to the same technical simplicity.

Then-Maryland Governor Martin O'Malley at an Annapolis rally to raise the minimum wage in January 2014. (Image by Maryland GovPics, via Flickr)

Seen this way, the neglect of the Fight for 15 by planning makes sense—it's about policy, organizing and distribution, issues seen to be increasingly removed from land use, design and transportation. But we pay a big price for that neglect. Ten years from now, cities with $15 wage floors will have developed in distinct ways. They will feature different mixes of industries and a more robust local consumption base, and they’ll have citizens more engaged in planning, politics and the development of their own long-term futures. These changes will be substantial, and I believe they will make clear the importance of community and economic development to all sub-fields of planning, if we learn to look for them.

Doussard, Marc. "Equity Planning Outside City Hall Rescaling Advocacy to Confront the Sources of Urban Problems." Journal of Planning Education and Research (2015): 0739456X15580021.

Dr. Doussard is Assistant Professor of Planning at University of Illinois.


JPER

In this new series, Journal of Planning Education and Research (JPER) articles will be made available to Planetizen readers subscription free for 30 days. This is possible through collaboration between SAGE Publications and the Association of Collegiate Schools of Planning.

Books

The Top Urban Planning Books of 2022

An annual list of the must-read books related to urban planning and its intersecting fields.

November 28, 2022 - James Brasuell

Urban separated bike lane with street trees on one side and cars parked on the other

How Urban Trees Save Lives

New research shows a strong connection between a healthy urban tree canopy and lowered mortality rates.

December 1, 2022 - Congress For New Urbanism

Houston, Construction

How To End Homelessness: The Houston Model

While the numbers of unhoused people in other major U.S. cities grow, Houston has managed to effectively end veteran homelessness and house more than 26,000 people since implementing a ‘Housing First’ approach a decade ago.

December 1, 2022 - Smart Cities Dive

Rendering of Juneteenth Museum

The Best, Worst, and Most Questionable in 2022 Architecture and Design

A list of innovative projects, intriguing design, and flummoxing failures.

December 6 - Medium

View of black oil wells behind chain link fence with barbed wire top

Los Angeles To Phase Out Oil Drilling

The city has banned new wells and will end all extraction within two decades.

December 6 - Los Angeles Times

Bus stop with passengers and bus in downtown Seattle

Puget Sound Transportation Plan Fails to Meet Climate Targets

Agency staff says the Puget Sound regional long-range plan won’t achieve 2030 sustainability goals set by the state.

December 6 - The Urbanist

Urban Design for Planners 1: Software Tools

This six-course series explores essential urban design concepts using open source software and equips planners with the tools they need to participate fully in the urban design process.

Planning for Universal Design

Learn the tools for implementing Universal Design in planning regulations.