The Economics of Rent Control

A simple explanation of why strict rent control reduces housing supply, and why moderate rent control does so to a much lesser extent.

4 minute read

September 21, 2015, 8:00 AM PDT

By Michael Lewyn @mlewyn


Bronx Apartments

Gregory James Van Raalte / Shutterstock

Economists oppose rent control almost as unanimously as climate scientists oppose attempts to deny the reality of client change. 93 percent of economists (including liberals like Paul Krugman) agree that ceilings on rents reduce the quantity and quality of housing. And economists' views seem borne out by experience: most major cities with rent control (such as New York and San Francisco) tend to have very high rents, indicating that rent control is perhaps not functioning as effectively as its creators had wished. And yet urban planners and citizen activists are much more closely divided. What do they not understand?

To understand the risks of rent control, imagine the strictest possible policy. Government freezes rents forever, prohibiting any landlord from increasing rents. As the costs of labor and utilities increase, landlords realize they are losing money by continuing to be landlords. So eventually landlords start to abandon property; if they cannot legally do so by converting apartments to condominiums, they do so illegally by letting property decay until a suspicious fire wipes out the landlords' problem. No new apartments replace these housing units, because no one will invest in housing if they can't make a profit by doing so. Eventually, renter-dominated areas turn into wastelands, like the South Bronx in the 1970s.  

Of course, no city has ever enacted such a strict policy. A more plausible form of rent control treats landlords as public utilities: government could limit rent increases rather than freezing rents, by providing that a landlord could increase rents by only a certain amount this year (say, the costs of increased landlord expenses). In this scenario, landlords will not abandon property as rapidly as in the first scenario. Nevertheless, this policy will still cap housing supply; even if existing landlords are less likely to jump ship, new landlords will be unlikely to enter the market. Here's why: rental housing competes with other, non-regulated investments. That is to say: if I have money that I could invest in (a) a business where my profits were capped by government (e.g. rental housing in this scenario) or (b) a business where government wants people to make huge profits (e.g., the stock market, single-family housing), I would, other things being equal, crazy to invest in (a). In this scenario, rent control creates housing shortages, much as Soviet centralized planning created shortages of consumer goods. 

Having said that, in reality rent control is not quite as toxic as in my hypothetical scenarios. In the United States, most cities with rent control do not regulate quite as intensively as in my hypotheticals; for example, in New York only older units are covered. Such "moderate rent control" does not reduce housing supply as much as would universal rent control, because it only caps rents in a limited slice of the market. On the other hand, this means that "moderate rent control" also doesn’t do much very much good—rents in New York are in fact sky-high for most people other than longtime residents. In other words, moderate rent control doesn't control rents very much. So what's the point?

Defenders of rent control point out that the correlation between rent control and housing supply is incomplete; for example, places that have removed rent control (such as Boston) have not always experienced construction booms, while highly regulated New York built lots of new housing in the 1950s. But this is to be expected from the above discussion of moderate rent control: if rent control is too weak to actually reduce rents, it is also going to be too weak to restrain supply as much as a policy that did reduce rents.  

And where rent control is relatively weak, it is just one factor affecting the supply of new housing: for example, zoning laws generally treat apartments as an undesirable use, and thus may restrain housing supply far more aggressively than moderate rent control. Conversely, if government allows lots of new housing construction, new housing will be built as long as rent control is not so strict as to prevent it. Similarly, if government subsidizes new housing or builds new housing itself, the positive results of such construction may be more important than the effects of moderate rent control.

In sum, the difference between strict rent control and moderate rent control is like the difference between smoking two packs of cigarettes a day and smoking two cigarettes a day. Smoking two packs of cigarettes a day, like strict rent control, is likely to create toxic results. Smoking two cigarettes a day, like moderate rent control, is far less harmful though still not ideal.


Michael Lewyn

Michael Lewyn is a professor at Touro University, Jacob D. Fuchsberg Law Center, in Long Island. His scholarship can be found at http://works.bepress.com/lewyn.

portrait of professional woman

I love the variety of courses, many practical, and all richly illustrated. They have inspired many ideas that I've applied in practice, and in my own teaching. Mary G., Urban Planner

I love the variety of courses, many practical, and all richly illustrated. They have inspired many ideas that I've applied in practice, and in my own teaching.

Mary G., Urban Planner

Cover CM Credits, Earn Certificates, Push Your Career Forward

Logo for Planetizen Federal Action Tracker with black and white image of U.S. Capitol with water ripple overlay.

Planetizen Federal Action Tracker

A weekly monitor of how Trump’s orders and actions are impacting planners and planning in America.

July 16, 2025 - Diana Ionescu

Green vintage Chicago streetcar from the 1940s parked at the Illinois Railroad Museum in 1988.

Chicago’s Ghost Rails

Just beneath the surface of the modern city lie the remnants of its expansive early 20th-century streetcar system.

July 13, 2025 - WTTV

Blue and silver Amtrak train with vibrant green and yellow foliage in background.

Amtrak Cutting Jobs, Funding to High-Speed Rail

The agency plans to cut 10 percent of its workforce and has confirmed it will not fund new high-speed rail projects.

July 14, 2025 - Smart Cities Dive

Worker in yellow safety vest and hard hat looks up at servers in data center.

Ohio Forces Data Centers to Prepay for Power

Utilities are calling on states to hold data center operators responsible for new energy demands to prevent leaving consumers on the hook for their bills.

July 18 - Inside Climate News

Former MARTA CEO Collie Greenwood standing in front of MARTA HQ with blurred MARTA sign visible in background.

MARTA CEO Steps Down Amid Citizenship Concerns

MARTA’s board announced Thursday that its chief, who is from Canada, is resigning due to questions about his immigration status.

July 18 - WABE

Rendering of proposed protected bikeway in Santa Clara, California.

Silicon Valley ‘Bike Superhighway’ Awarded $14M State Grant

A Caltrans grant brings the 10-mile Central Bikeway project connecting Santa Clara and East San Jose closer to fruition.

July 17 - San José Spotlight