The Unbounded Home

When you buy a house, you might think that you are in control of that house and its value.  But in reality, your house’s value depends on a wide variety of factors beyond your control, such as the perceived desirability of your neighbors, local highway and transit policies, and trends in national and regional housing markets.  Your home may be your castle in a physical sense- but its value is heavily affected by what goes on outside the residential setting. In her new book The Unbounded Home, University of Chicago law professor Lee Fennell addresses the implications of this reality and of homeowners’ attempts to reassert control over property values through restrictive covenants and zoning.

3 minute read

September 14, 2010, 7:57 AM PDT

By Michael Lewyn @mlewyn


When you buy a house, you might think that you are in
control of that house and its value.  But in reality, your house's value
depends on a wide variety of factors beyond your control, such as the
perceived desirability of your neighbors, local highway and transit
policies, and trends in national and regional housing markets.  Your
home may be your castle in a physical sense- but its value is heavily
affected by what goes on outside the residential setting.



In her new book The Unbounded Home, University of Chicago law professor
Lee Fennell addresses the implications of this reality and of
homeowners' attempts to reassert control over property values through
restrictive covenants and zoning.



Covenants are usually designed to protect property values by excluding
certain obnoxious activities.  Through covenants, homeowners contract to
give away some of their property rights in exchange for a veto power
over nearby homeowners' use of their property rights.  Zoning, by
contrast, involves municipal ordinances rather than enforceable private
contracts.



But under either system, a city or group of homeowners must either
absolutely prohibit or absolutely allow certain activities.  Fennell
points out that this approach often leads to inefficiencies- that is,
rules that create X amount of harm to one homeowner (or group of
homeowners) while creating less-than-X amount of benefit to others. 
Fennell suggests a statue of a gnome as an example.  Suppose Beasley
lives in a community that has banned yard art such as garden gnomes. 
Gnome privileges will win Beasley $600 in intangible psychic benefits,
an amount in excess of the $500 cost the gnomes will impose on the
community as a whole.    Fennell suggests that a more efficient system
would allow Beasley to install the gnome and compensate the community
for its "loss", thus resulting in a societal surplus of $100. However,
both zoning law and covenant law are not flexible enough to allow these
type of transactions.



Fennell suggests a variety of market-oriented solutions to the gnome
problem, and critiques each proposed solution. One simple option would
be to create fee schedules for rule violations; homeowners could pay for
the right to install gnomes.  But a set fee schedule might be too
inflexible, or lead to definitional problems. Fennell proposes a more
complex but possibly more equitable solution: using self-assessed
valuations to set fees.  Under this system, the homeowner would set the
value of his right to install gnomes, and the city or association would
have to either purchase his right or let him pay for the right.



At the end of the book, Fennell makes a broader attack on homeownership
as currently conceived.  She asks: if a buyer of ice cream doesn't have
to buy a stake in the company, why should the buyer of a home have to
purchase the risk of national and international housing trends?  The
current system forces homeowners to put nearly all of their capital in
one investment, thus creating economic catastrophe when house values
plummet.



As a remedy, Fennell proposes "Homeownership 2.0"- unbundling the
physical value of a home itself from the broader economic risks of the
housing market.  Ideally, investors would create financial products that
would allow a homeowner to alienate some of those risks.  For example,
an investor would sell a kind of insurance against declining property
values, promising to make up some of the difference between existing
values and a future price in exchange for an insurance premium.   Or the
investor would bet on housing price premiums, buying the right to
receive part of a house's appreciation; the homeowner would benefit by
using the money to invest in more diversified holdings.  But as Fennell
admits, there are "many [design issues] that would have to be confronted
in translating the H2.0 concept into a workable policy."   So someone else will have to do the detail work of figuring out how to make Homeownership 2.0 profitable.


Michael Lewyn

Michael Lewyn is a professor at Touro University, Jacob D. Fuchsberg Law Center, in Long Island. His scholarship can be found at http://works.bepress.com/lewyn.

courses user

As someone new to the planning field, Planetizen has been the perfect host guiding me into planning and our complex modern challenges. Corey D, Transportation Planner

As someone new to the planning field, Planetizen has been the perfect host guiding me into planning and our complex modern challenges.

Corey D, Transportation Planner

Ready to give your planning career a boost?

Broken, uneven sidewalk being damaged by large tree roots in Los Angeles, California.

The City of Broken Sidewalks

Can Los Angeles fix 4,000 miles of broken sidewalks before the city hosts the 2028 Olympic Games?

December 5, 2024 - Donald Shoup

Large store in mall with yellow and black STORE CLOSING sign on front.

Shifts in Shopping: Transforming Malls Into Parks

Maybe zombie malls still have a second life — one with a little greenery.

December 8, 2024 - Ruscena Wiederholt

Empty street and high-rise buildings in downtown Chicago, Illinois during COvid-19 pandemic.

Major US Cities Still Suffering Downtown Decline

Research shows that the “donut effect” hollowing out central business districts since the pandemic continues to cause economic decline in the 12 largest American cities.

December 3, 2024 - Stanford University News

Close-up of woman in flowered dress holding bar next to white porcelain sink in bathroom.

Survey: Americans Finding it Harder to ‘Age in Place’

While many people over 65 would prefer to stay in their homes and communities, high housing costs and a lack of accessible infrastructure make it difficult.

15 minutes ago - Smart Cities Dive

Sign for MASS MoCA on brick building.

Old Walls, New Homes

From forgotten buildings to thriving neighborhoods, adaptive reuse has the power to transform our cities.

1 hour ago - PlaceShakers

Dense informal settlement on steep hillside in Brazil.

Housing as a Climate Resilience Strategy

Ensuring that housing, including in informal settlements, is safe and healthy for its residents is a key tool in the fight to build more sustainable and equitable communities in the face of climate migration.

December 11 - Time Magazine

Urban Design for Planners 1: Software Tools

This six-course series explores essential urban design concepts using open source software and equips planners with the tools they need to participate fully in the urban design process.

Planning for Universal Design

Learn the tools for implementing Universal Design in planning regulations.

Write for Planetizen