Smart Growth and Housing Affordability – Round Three

I would like to expand an ongoing debate between Reason Foundation policy expert Samuel Staley and me concerning land use policy impacts on affordability and economic stability to include two additional issues: household economic resilience and wealth accumulation.  

5 minute read

April 4, 2009, 5:33 PM PDT

By Todd Litman


I would like to expand an ongoing debate between Reason Foundation policy expert Samuel Staley and me concerning land use policy impacts on affordability and economic stability to include two additional issues: household economic resilience and wealth accumulation.  

Background: Last month I posted a blog pointed out that smart growth can increase overall affordability by reducing total housing development costs, reducing public service costs and reducing transportation costs, while Staley argued that smart growth policies reduce housing affordabilty and so helps cause the global financial crisis. I responded with another blog that critiquing Staley's analysis (pointing out that correlations between urban growth boundaries and higher housing costs can be explained by the fact that they are generally implemented in areas with rapid growth where land prices are increasing), and provided additional evidence of smart growth economic savings and higher home foreclosure rates in sprawled areas. Staley responded with a defence of his analysis but failed to respond to any other points I had raised, particularly the higher transportation costs of sprawled locations which offset any housing cost savings.

I believe that lower-density, automobile-dependent residential development is even more harmful than indicated in these previous discussions because it exposes households to financial risks and reduces their real estate equity, both of which contributed to the current economic crisis. Put more positively, smart growth helps increase household economic resilience and long-term wealth. This debate concerns the trade-offs households make between cheaper housing and higher transportation costs at the urban fringe and their long-term economic impacts.

First, let's consider the financial risks to households of choosing an automobile-dependent home. Staley's evidence indicating that smart growth areas have higher foreclosure rates is based on highly aggregated data (entire urban regions). More fine-grained analysis, within urban regions, shows much higher foreclosure rates in sprawled location than more central locations. The figure below illustrates this pattern for the city of Houston. Similar patterns are found elsewhere.

 

 

 Houston Region Housing Foreclosures

Houston region housing foreclosure rates are much higher at the urban fringe,

indicating that sprawl increases household financial risks. (Houston Chronicle)

 

These higher foreclosure rates can be explained by the additional financial risks associated with automobile dependency. In urban fringe locations, every adult must own an automobile and drive high annual miles. As a result, they are vulnerable to common economic risks: a major vehicle failure or crash, fuel price spikes, a disability, or reduced household income (such as the loss of a job). In contrast, residents of more accessible locations with more diverse transportation systems can respond by reducing their vehicle ownership and relying more on walking, cycling and public transportation, saving thousands of dollars a year. A more accessible location also improves access to well-paying jobs and education opportunities. Households in smart growth locations are therefore more economically resilient. This is particularly important now that so many households are experiencing financial turmoil.

The Institute for Location Efficiency has extensive information on the additional financial costs to consumers of more automobile-dependent, sprawled locations and the savings that they can gain from improved accessibility. They predicted for years that homes in more accessible, multi-modal locations are more financially secure, the current foreclosure crisis has proven that theory.

Second, consider the impacts of automobile dependency on long-term household wealth generation. Motor vehicles depreciate while houses tend to appreciate and so build household wealth.

For example, imagine that a household must choose between a suburban house with a $12,000 annual mortgage and $12,000 annual transportation costs, or an urban house with a $18,000 annual mortgage with only $6,000 in annual transportation costs. Both total $24,000 in combined housing and transportation costs, so they are economically comparable in the short-run. However, money spent on housing builds equity while money spent on motor vehicles does not. As a result, over the long run the urban location provides the household with 50% more equity, probably even more since rising future fuel prices and changing consumer preferences are likely to cause urban housing to appreciate much more than suburban housing during the next two decades. As a result, a typical household is likely to be a hundred thousand dollars wealthier in a decade if they choose a smart growth location over automobile-dependent sprawl.  

These give additional support to my previous argument that smart growth is economically superior overall. I am not suggesting that suburban development be prohibited, but it is economically wasteful and cruel to lower-income households to continue public policies that encourage sprawl and discourage smart growth, such as restrictions on development density and multi-family housing, minimum parking supply and setback requirements, and public subsidy of urban fringe infrastructure expansion. Development fees, utility fees and municipal property taxes should reflect the higher costs of providing public services (roads, utilities, emergency response and school busing) in urban fringe locations, so fees and taxes are lower in smart growth locations.

 

I appreciate comments on this analysis. 

 

For more information see: 

Danielle Arigoni (2001), Affordable Housing and Smart Growth: Making the Connections, Subgroup on Affordable Housing, Smart Growth Network (www.smartgrowth.org) and National Neighborhood Coalition (www.neighborhoodcoalition.org).

Scott Bernstein, Carrie Makarewicz, Kara Heffernan, Albert Benedict and Ben Helphand (2004), Increasing Affordability Through Reducing the Transportation and Infrastructure Cost Burdens of Housing, Atlanta Neighborhood Development Partnerships (www.andpi.org); at www.andpi.org/uploadedFiles/pdf/03MICI%20MTC%20Report_CNT.pdf.

CTOD (2009), Mixed-Income Housing TOD Action Guide, Center for Transit Oriented Development (CTOD) for Reconnecting America, the Center for Neighborhood Technology (www.reconnectingamerica.org); at http://reconnectingamerica.org/public/display_asset/090304mitodag0109.

Peter M. Haas, Carrie Makarewicz, Albert Benedict, Thomas W. Sanchez and Casey J. Dawkins (2006), Housing & Transportation Cost Trade-offs and Burdens of Working Households in 28 Metros, Center for Neighborhood Technology (www.cnt.org); at www.cnt.org/repository/H-T-Tradeoffs-for-Working-Families-n-28-Metros-FULL.pdf.

Barbara Lipman (2006), A Heavy Load: The Combined Housing and Transportation Burdens of Working Families, Center for Housing Policy (www.nhc.org/pdf/pub_heavy_load_10_06.pdf).

Todd Litman (2005), Understanding Smart Growth Saving, VTPI (www.vtpi.org); at www.vtpi.org/sg_save.pdf.

Todd Litman (2006), Smart Growth Policy Reforms, VTPI (www.vtpi.org); at www.vtpi.org/smart_growth_reforms.pdf. 

Todd Litman (2007), Transportation Affordability: Evaluation and Improvement Strategies, VTPI (www.vtpi.org); at www.vtpi.org/affordability.pdf.

Arthur C. Nelson, Rolf Pendall, Casy Dawkins and Gerrit Knaap (2002), The Link Between Growth Management and Housing Affordability: The Academic Evidence, Brookings Institution Center on Urban and Metropolitan Policy (www.brook.edu); at www.brook.edu/dybdocroot/es/urban/publications/growthmang.pdf.

STPP (2003), Transportation Costs and the American Dream: Why a Lack of Transportation Choices Strains the Family Budget and Hinders Home Ownership, Surface Transportation Policy Project (www.transact.org). MWCOG (2005), Toolkit for Affordable Housing Development, Metropolitan Washington Council of Governments (www.mwcog.org), Publication Number: 20058254; at www.mwcog.org/uploads/pub-documents/9VpbXg20060217144716.pdf.


Todd Litman

Todd Litman is founder and executive director of the Victoria Transport Policy Institute, an independent research organization dedicated to developing innovative solutions to transport problems. His work helps to expand the range of impacts and options considered in transportation decision-making, improve evaluation methods, and make specialized technical concepts accessible to a larger audience. His research is used worldwide in transport planning and policy analysis.

Sweeping view of Portland, Oregon with Mt. Hood in background against sunset sky.

Oregon Passes Exemption to Urban Growth Boundary

Cities have a one-time chance to acquire new land for development in a bid to increase housing supply and affordability.

March 12, 2024 - Housing Wire

Aerial view of green roofs with plants in Sydney, Australia.

Where Urban Design Is Headed in 2024

A forecast of likely trends in urban design and architecture.

March 10, 2024 - Daily Journal of Commerce

Cobblestone street with streetcar line, row of vintage streetlights on left, and colorful restaurant and shop awnings on right on River Street in Savannah, Georgia.

Savannah: A City of Planning Contrasts

From a human-scales, plaza-anchored grid to suburban sprawl, the oldest planned city in the United States has seen wildly different development patterns.

March 12, 2024 - Strong Towns

Aerial View of Chuckanut Drive and the Blanchard Bridge in the Skagit Valley.

Washington Tribes Receive Resilience Funding

The 28 grants support projects including relocation efforts as coastal communities face the growing impacts of climate change.

March 18 - The Seattle Times

Historic buildings in downtown Los Angeles with large "Pan American Lofts" sign on side of building.

Adaptive Reuse Bills Introduced in California Assembly

The legislation would expand eligibility for economic incentives and let cities loosen regulations to allow for more building conversions.

March 18 - Beverly Press

View from above of swan-shaped paddleboats with lights on around artesian fountain in Echo Park Lake with downtown Los Angeles skylien in background at twilight.

LA's Top Parks, Ranked

TimeOut just released its list of the top 26 parks in the L.A. area, which is home to some of the best green spaces around.

March 18 - TimeOut

News from HUD User

HUD's Office of Policy Development and Research

Call for Speakers

Mpact Transit + Community

New Updates on PD&R Edge

HUD's Office of Policy Development and Research

Write for Planetizen

Urban Design for Planners 1: Software Tools

This six-course series explores essential urban design concepts using open source software and equips planners with the tools they need to participate fully in the urban design process.

Planning for Universal Design

Learn the tools for implementing Universal Design in planning regulations.