The Theory of NIMBYism, Part 2

Homeowners' desire for more expensive land does not justify the "NIMBY veto" over new development.

3 minute read

May 5, 2014, 8:22 AM PDT

By Michael Lewyn @mlewyn


NIMBY Toilet Sign

J / Flickr

When I posted about the logic (and illogic) of NIMBYism in March, I got a bucketful of responses on this blog—some friendly, some hostile.

One of the most interesting critiques of my article asserted that zoning "protects property values and assures a measure of continuity. If you want people to invest their hard-earned dollars in buying and improving properties in your city, you are going to have to accept the fact that those property owners are going to want a voice when future developments that will impact them, their property and their neighborhood are considered." In other words, if homeowners get a veto over new development, they (1) are more likely to invest in land because if so they (2) will benefit from increased property values.

The first argument seems persuasive on the surface; in the 1920s real estate developers often favored zoning because it would "protect" their investments from allegedly incompatible uses. Nevertheless, landowners are in fact perfectly willing to invest in places without zoning. American cities were able to develop and expand without much difficulty before zoning—and in Houston (which lacks a formal zoning code)* housing development is actually more common than in some highly restrictive cities. Between 2006 and 2010, the number of residential building permits in Houston ranged between 12 and 38 per 1000 people—lower than the statewide average, but higher than in many other urban centers, including highly restrictive San Francisco and similar-but-zoned cities such as Dallas.

The second argument has a stronger element of truth; it does seem to me that highly restrictive zoning allows homeowners to essentially form a cartel, restricting the supply of homes and apartments and raising rent and housing prices (or to use a more widely accepted euphemism "property values"). To draw an analogy: if government allowed Target and Wal-Mart to veto all new stores within a mile of any Target or Wal-Mart, the prices of all goods sold by Target and Wal-Mart would certainly rise. 

But do you really want to live in a society where zoning-as-cartel succeeds? In places like San Francisco and New York, a complex and restrictive zoning process contributes to sky-high housing prices, which in turn means that many middle-class people feel forced to move out of the city, and lower-class people who cannot afford high rents sleep in homeless shelters or on the streets. And because multifamily housing is nearly always more controversial than single-family housing, zoning affects rents even more than it affects home prices. Why, as a moral matter, should government price the poor and middle class out of the market so that existing homeowners can sell their houses for more? Or to go back to the Wal-Mart analogy: if Wal-Mart and Target persuaded zoning boards to prohibit competition from grocery stores and then raised food prices so high that poor and middle-class families were malnourished, would we consider this a morally acceptable result?

Moreover, zoning hasn't always succeeded in its aim of raising property values. In the 1920s, most Americans protected by zoning lived in what we would today call urban and inner suburban neighborhoods. Some of those neighborhoods have always had stable property values—but others witnessed a catastrophic drop in property values in the second half of the 20th century, as "white flight" (and later "black middle-class flight") reduced demand for housing. And in the 2000s, the collapse of a housing bubble has led to drops in housing prices over the last five or ten years. Even in supposedly gentrifying Brooklyn, housing prices in some places are lower than in 2004. Thus, zoning occasionally fails even by its own criteria.

In sum, zoning doesn't always increase property values—and when it does, it sometimes is too successful.

*One common counterargument is that Houston's low housing prices are the result of highway-induced sprawl, and that it may be impossible to have lower housing prices without high transportation costs. I note that other cities with zoning have equally car-dependent urban form.


Michael Lewyn

Michael Lewyn is an associate professor at Touro University, Jacob D. Fuchsberg Law Center, in Long Island. His scholarship can be found at http://works.bepress.com/lewyn.

Aerial view of homes on green hillsides in Daly City, California.

Depopulation Patterns Get Weird

A recent ranking of “declining” cities heavily features some of the most expensive cities in the country — including New York City and a half-dozen in the San Francisco Bay Area.

April 10, 2024 - California Planning & Development Report

Aerial view of Oakland, California with bay in background

California Exodus: Population Drops Below 39 Million

Never mind the 40 million that demographers predicted the Golden State would reach by 2018. The state's population dipped below 39 million to 38.965 million last July, according to Census data released in March, the lowest since 2015.

April 11, 2024 - Los Angeles Times

A view straight down LaSalle Street, lined by high-rise buildings with an El line running horizontally over the street.

Chicago to Turn High-Rise Offices into Housing

Four commercial buildings in the Chicago Loop have been approved for redevelopment into housing in a bid to revitalize the city’s downtown post-pandemic.

April 10, 2024 - Chicago Construction News

Officials cutting a ceremonial red ribbon at Skyline Ranch Park in Santa Clarita, California.

New Park Opens in the Santa Clarita Valley

The City of Santa Clarita just celebrated the grand opening of its 38th park, the 10.5-acre Skyline Ranch Park.

April 18 - The Signal

Workers putting down asphalt on road.

U.S. Supreme Court: California's Impact Fees May Violate Takings Clause

A California property owner took El Dorado County to state court after paying a traffic impact fee he felt was exorbitant. He lost in trial court, appellate court, and the California Supreme Court denied review. Then the U.S. Supreme Court acted.

April 18 - Los Angeles Times

Aerial view of Barcelona, Spain with Sagrada Familia church in middle among dense buildings.

How Urban Form Impacts Housing Affordability

The way we design cities affects housing costs differently than you might think.

April 18 - The Conversation

News from HUD User

HUD's Office of Policy Development and Research

Call for Speakers

Mpact Transit + Community

New Updates on PD&R Edge

HUD's Office of Policy Development and Research

Write for Planetizen

Urban Design for Planners 1: Software Tools

This six-course series explores essential urban design concepts using open source software and equips planners with the tools they need to participate fully in the urban design process.

Planning for Universal Design

Learn the tools for implementing Universal Design in planning regulations.